Home » The City as a Growth Machine Article Review

The City as a Growth Machine Article Review

The City as a Growth Machine: Toward a Political Economy of Place Author(s): Harvey Molotch Source: American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 82, No. 2 (Sep., 1976), pp. 309-332 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2777096 Accessed: 05-02-2018 22:20 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide

Don't use plagiarized sources. Get Your Custom Essay on
The City as a Growth Machine Article Review
Just from $9/Page
Order Essay

range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and

facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

 

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

http://about.jstor.org/terms

The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Sociology

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine: Toward a

Political Economy of Place’

Harvey Molotch

University of California, Santa Barbara

A city and, more generally, any locality, is conceived as the areal expression of the interests of some land-based elite. Such an elite is seen to profit through the increasing intensification of the land use of the area in which its members hold a common interest. An elite competes with other land-based elites in an effort to have growth-inducing resources invested within its own area as opposed to that of another. Governmental authority, at the local and nonlocal levels, is utilized to assist in achieving this growth at the expense of competing localities. Conditions of community life are largely a con- sequence of the social, economic, and political forces embodied in this growth machine. The relevance of growth to the interests of various social groups is examined in this context, particularly with reference to the issue of unemployment. Recent social trends in opposition to growth are described and their potential consequences evaluated.

Conventional definitions of “city,” “urban place,” or “metropolis” have led to conventional analyses of urban systems and urban-based social

problems. Usually traceable to Wirth’s classic and highly plausible formu-

lation of “numbers, density and heterogeneity” (1938), there has been

a continuing tendency, even in more recent formulations (e.g., Davis

1965), to conceive of place quite apart from a crucial dimension of social

structure: power and social class hierarchy. Consequently, sociological

research based on the traditional definitions of what an urban place is has

had very little relevance to the actual, day-to-day activities of those at the

top of local power structure whose priorities set the limits within which

decisions affecting land use, the public budget, and urban social life come

to be made. It has not been very apparent from the scholarship of urban

social science that land, the basic stuff of place, is a market commodity

providing wealth and power, and that some very important people conse-

quently take a keen interest in it. Thus, although there are extensive litera-

tures on community power as well as on how to define and conceptualize

a city or urban place, there are few notions available to link the two issues

coherently, focusing on the urban settlement as a political economy.

This paper aims toward filling this need. I speculate that the political

1 I have had the benefit of critical comments and assistance from Richard Appelbaum, Richard Baisden, Norman Bowers, Norton Long, Howard Newby, Anthony Shih, Tony Pepitone, Gerald Suttles, Gaye Tuchman, and Al Wyner.

AJS Volume 82 Number 2 309

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

and economic essence of virtually any given locality, in the present Amer-

ican context, is growth. I further argue that the desire for growth provides

the key operative motivation toward consensus for members of politically

mobilized local elites, however split they might be on other issues, and

that a common interest in growth is the overriding commonality among

important people in a given locale-at least insofar as they have any

important local goals at all. Further, this growth imperative is the most

important constraint upon available options for local initiative in social

and economic reform. It is thus that I argue that the very essence of a

locality is its operation as a growth machine.

The clearest indication of success at growth is a constantly rising

urban-area population-a symptom of a pattern ordinarily comprising an

initial expansion of basic industries followed by an expanded labor force,

a rising scale of retail and wholesale commerce, more far-flung and in-

creasingly intensive land development, higher population density, and

increased levels of financial activity. Although throughout this paper I

index growth by the variable population growth, it is this entire syndrome

of associated events that is meant by the general term “growth.”2 I argue

that the means of achieving this growth, of setting off this chain of phe- nomena, constitute the central issue for those serious people who care

about their locality and who have the resources to make their caring felt

as a political force. The city is, for those who count, a growth machine.

THE HUMAN ECOLOGY: MAPS AS INTEREST MOSAICS

I have argued elsewhere (Molotch 1967, 1973) that any given parcel of

land represents an interest and that any given locality is thus an aggregate

of land-based interests. That is, each landowner (or person who otherwise

has some interest in the prospective use of a given piece of land) has in

mind a certain future for that parcel which is linked somehow with his or

her own well-being. If there is a simple ownership, the relationship is

2 This association of related phenomena is the common conceptualization which students of the economic development of cities ordinarily utilize in their analyses (see, e.g., Alonso 1964, pp. 79-81; Leven 1964, pp. 140-44; Brown 1974, pp. 48-51; and Durr 1971, pp. 174-80). As Sunquist remarks in the context of his study of population policies in Western Europe, “The key to population distribution is, of course, job availability. A few persons-retired, notably, and some independent pro- fessionals such as artists, writers and inventors-may be free to live in any locality they choose but, for the rest, people are compelled to distribute themselves in what- ever pattern is dictated by the distribution of employment opportunities. Some investors may locate their investment in areas of surplus labour voluntarily, and so check the migration flow, and others may be induced by government assistance to do so. But if neither of these happens-if the jobs do not go where the workers are -the workers must go to the jobs, if they are not to accept welfare as a way of life. When population distribution is an end, then, job distribution is inevitably the means” (1975, p. 13).

310

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

straightforward: to the degree to which the land’s profit potential is

enhanced, one’s own wealth is increased. In other cases, the relationship

may be more subtle: one has interest in an adjacent parcel, and if a

noxious use should appear, one’s own parcel may be harmed. More subtle

still is the emergence of concern for an aggregate of parcels: one sees that

one’s future is bound to the future of a larger area, that the future enjoy-

ment of financial benefit flowing from a given parcel will derive from the

general future of the proximate aggregate of parcels. When this occurs,

there is that “we feeling” (McKenzie 1922) which bespeaks of com-

munity. We need to see each geographical map-whether of a small group

of land parcels, a whole city, a region, or a nation-not merely as a de-

marcation of legal, political, or topographical features, but as a mosaic

of competing land interests capable of strategic coalition and action.

Each unit of a community strives, at the expense of the others, to

enhance the land-use potential of the parcels with which it is associated.

Thus, for example, shopkeepers at both ends of a block may compete with

one another to determine in front of which building the bus stop will be

placed. Or, hotel owners on the north side of a city may compete with

those on the south to get a convention center built nearby (see Banfield

1961). Likewise, area units fight over highway routes, airport locations,

campus developments, defense contracts, traffic lights, one-way street

designations, and park developments. The intensity of group consciousness

and activity waxes and wanes as opportunities for and challenges to the

collective good rise and fall; but when these coalitions are of sufficiently

enduring quality, they constitute identifiable, ongoing communities. Each

member of a community is simultaneously the member of a number of

others; hence, communities exist in a nested fashion (e.g., neighborhood

within city within region), with salience of community level varying both

over time and circumstance. Because of this nested nature of communities,

subunits which are competitive with one another at one level (e.g., in an

interblock dispute over where the bus stop should go) will be in coalition

at a higher level (e.g., in an intercity rivalry over where the new port

should go). Obviously, the anticipation of potential coalition acts to con-

strain the intensity of conflict at more local loci of growth competition.

Hence, to the degree to which otherwise competing land-interest groups

collude to achieve a common land-enhancement scheme, there is com-

munity-whether at the level of a residential block club, a neighborhood

association, a city or metropolitan chamber of commerce, a state develop-

ment agency, or a regional association. Such aggregates, whether consti-

tuted formally or informally, whether governmental political institutions

or voluntary associations, typically operate in the following way: an at-

tempt is made to use government to gain those resources which will

enhance the growth potential of the area unit in question. Often, the

311

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

governmental level where action is needed is at least one level higher than

the community from which the activism springs. Thus, individual land-

owners aggregate to extract neighborhood gains from the city government;

a cluster of cities may coalesce to have an effective impact on the state

government, etc. Each locality, in striving to make these gains, is in com-

petition with other localities because the degree of growth, at least at any

given moment, is finite. The scarcity of developmental resources means

that government becomes the arena in which land-use interest groups com-

pete for public money and attempt to mold those decisions which will deter-

mine the land-use outcomes. Localities thus compete with one another to

gain the preconditions of growth. Historically, U.S. cities were created and

sustained largely through this process;3 it continues to be the significant

dynamic of contemporary local political economy and is critical to the

allocation of public resources and the ordering of local issue agendas.

Government decisions are not the only kinds of social activities which

affect local growth chances; decisions made by private corporations also

have major impact. When a national corporation decides to locate a

branch plant in a given locale, it sets the conditions for the surrounding

land-use pattern. But even here, government decisions are involved: plant- location decisions are made with reference to such issues as labor costs,

tax rates, and the costs of obtaining raw materials and transporting goods

to markets. It is government decisions (at whatever level) that help deter-

mine the cost of access to markets and raw materials. This is especially

so in the present era of raw material subsidies (e.g., the mineral depletion

allowance) and reliance on government approved or subsidized air trans-

port, highways, railways, pipelines, and port developments. Government

decisions influence the cost of overhead expenses (e.g., pollution abatement

requirements, employee safety standards), and government decisions affect

the costs of labor through indirect manipulation of unemployment rates,

through the use of police to constrain or enhance union organizing, and

through the legislation and administration of welfare laws (see Piven and

Cloward 1972).

Localities are generally mindful of these governmental powers and, in

addition to creating the sorts of physical conditions which can best serve

industrial growth, also attempt to maintain the kind of “business climate”

that attracts industry: for example, favorable taxation, vocational train-

ing, law enforcement, and “good” labor relations. To promote growth,

taxes should be “reasonable,” the police force should be oriented toward

protection of property, and overt social conflict should be minimized (see

3 For accounts of how “boosterism” worked in this manner, see Wade (1969) and

Harris (1976).

312

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

Rubin 1972, p. 123; Agger, Goldrich, and Swanson 1964, p. 649).4 In-

creased utility and government costs caused by new development should

be borne (and they usually are-see, e.g., Ann Arbor City Planning De-

partment [1972]) by the public at large, rather than by those responsible

for the “excess” demand on the urban infrastructure. Virtually any issue

of a major business magazine is replete with ads from localities of all types

(including whole countries) trumpeting their virtues in just these terms

to prospective industrial settlers.5 In addition, a key role of elected and

appointed officials becomes that of “ambassador” to industry, to communi-

cate, usually with appropriate ceremony, these advantages to potential

investors (see Wyner 1967).6

I aim to make the extreme statement that this organized effort to affect

the outcome of growth distribution is the essence of local government as

a dynamic political force. It is not the only function of government, but it

is the key one and, ironically, the one most ignored. Growth is not, in the

present analysis, merely one among a number of equally important con-

cerns of political process (cf. Adrian and Williams 1963). Among con-

temporary social scientists, perhaps only Murray Edelman (1964) has

provided appropriate conceptual preparation for viewing government in

such terms. Edelman contrasts two kinds of politics. First there is the

“symbolic” politics which comprises the “big issues” of public morality

and the symbolic reforms featured in the headlines and editorials of the

daily press. The other politics is the process through which goods and

services actually come to be distributed in the society. Largely unseen,

and relegated to negotiations within committees (when it occurs at all within a formal government body), this is the politics which determines

who, in material terms, gets what, where, and how (Lasswell 1936). This

is the kind of politics we must talk about at the local level: it is the politics

4 Agger et al. remark, on the basis of their comparative study of four U.S cities: “[Members of the local elites] value highly harmony and unity-‘pulling together.’ They regard local community affairs as essentially nonpolitical, and tend to associate controversy with ‘politics.’ An additional factor reinforcing the value of harmony in many communities . . . is the nationwide competition among communities for new industries. Conflict is thought to create a highly unfavourable image to outsiders, an image that might well repel any prospective industry” (1964, p. 649).

5 See, e.g., the May 19, 1974, issue of Forbes, which had the following ad placed by the State of Pennsylvania: “Q: [banner headline] What state could possibly cut taxes at a time like this? A: Pennsylvania [same large type]. Pennsylvania intends to keep showing businessmen that it means business. Pennsylvania. Where business has a lot growing for it. . . .” The state of Maryland ran this ad in the same issue: “Maryland Finances the Training. . . In short, we can finance practically everything you need to establish a manufacturing plant. . ..”

6 The city of Los Angeles maintains an office, headed by a former key business exec- utive, with this “liaison” role as its specific task (see “L.A.’s Business Envoy Speaks Softly and Sits at a Big Desk,” Los Angeles Times [August 26, 1974]).

313

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

of distribution, and land is the crucial (but not the only) variable in this

system.

The people who participate with their energies, and particularly their

fortunes, in local affairs are the sort of persons who-at least in vast dis-

proportion to their representation in the population-have the most to gain

or lose in land-use decisions. Prominent in terms of numbers have long

been the local businessmen (see Walton 1970) ,7 particularly property

owners and investors in locally oriented financial institutions (see, e.g.,

Spaulding 1951; Mumford 1961, p. 536), who need local government in their daily money-making routines. Also prominent are lawyers, syndica-

tors, and realtors (see Bouma 1962) who need to put themselves in situa-

tions where they can be most useful to those with the land and property

resources.8 Finally, there are those who, although not directly involved in

land use, have their futures tied to growth of the metropolis as a whole.

At least, when the local market becomes saturated one of the few possible

avenues for business expansion is sometimes the expansion of the sur-

rounding community itself (see Adrian and Williams 1963, p. 24).9

This is the general outline of the coalition that actively generates the

community “we feeling” (or perhaps more aptly, the “our feeling”)10 that

comes to be an influence in the politics of a given locality. It becomes

manifest through a wide variety of techniques. Government funds support

“boosterism” of various sorts: the Chamber of Commerce, locality-promo-

tion ads in business journals and travel publications, city-sponsored parade

7 The literature on community power is vast and controversial but has been sum- marized by Walton: he indicates, on the basis of 39 studies of 61 communities, that “the proportion of businessmen found in the leadership group is high irrespective of the type of power structure found” (1970, p. 446). It is my argument, of course, that this high level of participation does indeed indicate the exercise of power on behalf of at least a portion of the elite. My analysis does not assume that this portion of the elite is necessarily always united with others of high status on the concrete issues of local land use and the uses of local government.

8Descriptions of some tactics typically employed in land-use politics are contained in McConnell (1966), Tolchin and Tolchin (1971), and Makielski (1966), but a sophisticated relevant body of literature does not yet exist.

9 Thus the stance taken by civic business groups toward growth and land-use matters affecting growth is consistently positive, although the intensity of commitment to that goal varies. In his study of New York City zoning, Makielski indicates that “the general business groups . . . approached zoning from an economic viewpoint, although this often led them to share the Reformer’s ideology. Their economic interest in the city gave them a stake in a ‘healthy,’ ‘growing community’ where tax rates were not prohibitive, where city government was ‘efficient,’ and where some of the problems of the urban environment-a constricting labour force, congestion, and lack of space -were being attacked” (1966, p. 141). A similar dynamic has been observed in a medium-size Mexican city: “Despite many other differences, basic agreement on the primacy of stability and growth provides a basis for a dialogue between government and business” (Fagen and Tuohy 1972, p. 56).

10 Bruce Pringle suggested the latter phrase to me.

314

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

floats, and stadia and other forms of support for professional sports teams

carrying the locality name. The athletic teams in particular are an extra-

ordinary mechanism for instilling a spirit of civic jingoism regarding the

“progress” of the locality. A stadium filled with thousands (joined by

thousands more at home before the TV) screaming for Cleveland or

Baltimore (or whatever) is a scene difficult to fashion otherwise. This

enthusiasm can be drawn upon, with a glossy claim of creating a “greater

Cleveland,” “greater Baltimore,” etc., in order to gain general acceptance

for local growth-oriented programs. Similarly, public school curricula,

children’s essay contests, soapbox derbies, spelling contests, beauty pag-

eants, etc., help build an ideological base for local boosterism and the

acceptance of growth. My conception of the territorial bond among hu-

mans differs from those cast in terms of primordial instincts: instead, I

see this bond as socially organized and sustained, at least in part, by

those who have a use for it (cf. Suttles 1972, pp. 111-39). I do not claim

that there are no other sources of civic jingoism and growth enthusiasm

in American communities, only that the growth-machine coalition mobilizes

what is there, legitimizes and sustains it, and channels it as a political

force into particular kinds of policy decisions.

The local institution which seems to take prime responsibility for the

sustenance of these civic resources-the metropolitan newspaper-is also

the most important example of a business which has its interest anchored

in the aggregate growth of the locality. Increasingly, American cities are

one-newspaper (metropolitan daily) towns (or one-newspaper-company

towns), and the newspaper business seems to be one kind of enterprise

for which expansion to other locales is especially difficult. The financial

loss suffered by the New York Times in its futile effort to establish a

California edition is an important case in point. A paper’s financial status

(and that of other media to a lesser extent) tends to be wed to the size

of the locality.” As the metropolis expands, a larger number of ad lines

can be sold on the basis of the increasing circulation base. The local news

paper thus tends to occupy a rather unique position: like many other local

businesses, it has an interest in growth, but unlike most, its critical interest

is not in the specific geographical pattern of that growth. That is, the cru-

cial matter to a newspaper is not whether the additional population comes to reside on the north side or south side, or whether the money is made

through a new convention center or a new olive factory. The newspaper

has no axe to grind, except the one axe which holds the community elite

together: growth. It is for this reason that the newspaper tends to achieve

11 Papers can expand into other industries, such as book publishing and wood har- vesting. The point is that, compared with most other industries, they cannot easily replicate themselves across geographical boundaries through chains, branch plants, and franchises.

315

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

a statesman-like attitude in the community and is deferred to as something

other than a special interest by the special interests. Competing interests often regard the publisher or editor as a general community leader, as an

ombudsman and arbiter of internal bickering and, at times, as an en- lightened third party who can restrain the short-term profiteers in the

interest of more stable, long-term, and properly planned growth.12 The

paper becomes the reformist influence, the “voice of the community,” restraining the competing subunits, especially the small-scale, arriviste

“fast-buck artists” among them. The papers are variously successful in

their continuous battle with the targeted special interests.’3 The media attempt to attain these goals not only through the kind of coverage they

develop and editorials they write but also through the kinds of candidates

they support for local office. The present point is not that the papers con- trol the politics of the city, but rather that one of the sources of their special influence is their commitment to growth per se, and growth is a goal around which all important groups can rally.

Thus it is that, although newspaper editorialists have typically been in the forefront expressing sentiment in favor of “the ecology,” they tend nevertheless to support growth-inducing investments for their regions. The New York Times likes office towers and additional industrial installations in the city even more than it loves the environment. The Los Angeles Times editorializes against narrow-minded profiteering at the expense of

the environment but has also favored the development of the supersonic transport because of the “jobs” it would lure to Southern California. The papers do tend to support “good planning principles” in some form be- cause such good planning is a long-term force that makes for even more potential future growth. If the roads are not planned wide enough, their narrowness will eventually strangle the increasingly intense uses to which the land will be put. It just makes good sense to plan, and good planning for “sound growth” thus is the key “environmental policy” of the nation’s local media and their statesmen allies. Such policies of “good planning” should not be confused with limited growth or conservation: they more

typically represent the opposite sort of goal. Often leaders of public or quasi-public agencies (e.g., universities,

utilities) achieve a role similar to that of the newspaper publisher: they become growth “statesmen” rather than advocates for a certain type or

12 In some cities (e.g., Chicago) it is the political machine that performs this func- tion and thus can “get things done.” Political scientists (e.g., Edward Banfield) often identify success in performing this function as evidence of effective local government.

13 In his study of the history of zoning in New York City, Makielski remarks: “While the newspapers in the city are large landholders, the role of the press was not quite like that of any of the other nongovernmental actors. The press was in part one of the referees of the rules of the game, especially the informal rules-calling attention to what it considered violations” (1966, p. 189).

316

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

intralocal distribution of growth. A university may require an increase in

the local urban population pool to sustain its own expansion plans and, in addition, it may be induced to defer to others in the growth machine

(bankers, newspapers) upon whom it depends for the favorable financial

and public-opinion environment necessary for institutional enhancement.

There are certain persons, ordinarily conceived of as members of the

elite, who have much less, if any, interest in local growth. Thus, for exam-

ple, there are branch executives of corporations headquartered elsewhere

who, although perhaps emotionally sympathetic with progrowth outlooks,

work for corporations which have no vested interest in the growth of the

locality in question. Their indirect interest is perhaps in the existence of

the growth ideology rather than growth itself. It is that ideology which in

fact helps make them revered people in the area (social worth is often de-

fined in terms of number of people one employs) and which provides the

rationale for the kind of local governmental policies most consistent with

low business operating costs. Nonetheless, this interest is not nearly as

strong as the direct growth interests of developers, mortgage bankers, etc.,

and thus we find, as Schulze (1961) has observed, that there is a tendency

for such executives to play a lesser local role than the parochial, home-

grown businessmen whom they often replace.

Thus, because the city is a growth machine, it draws a special sort of

person into its politics. These people-whether acting on their own or on

behalf of the constituency which financed their rise to power-tend to be

businessmen and, among businessmen, the more parochial sort. Typically,

they come to politics not to save or destroy the environment, not to repress or liberate the blacks, not to eliminate civil liberties or enhance them. They

may end up doing any or all of these things once they have achieved access

to authority, perhaps as an inadvertent consequence of making decisions

in other realms. But these types of symbolic positions are derived from the

fact of having power-they are typically not the dynamics which bring

people to power in the first place. Thus, people often become “involved” in government, especially in the local party structure and fund raising, for

reasons of land business and related processes of resource distribution.

Some are “statesmen” who think in terms of the growth of the whole com- munity rather than that of a more narrow geographical delimitation. But

they are there to wheel and deal to affect resource distribution through local government. As a result of their position, and in part to develop the

symbolic issues which will enable them (in lieu of one of their opponents

or colleagues) to maintain that position of power, they get interested in

such things as welfare cheating, busing, street crime, and the price of meat.

This interest in the symbolic issues (see Edelman 1964) is thus substan-

tially an aftereffect of a need for power for other purposes. This is not to say that such people don’t “feel strongly” about these matters-they do

317

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

sometimes. It is also the case that certain moral zealots and “concerned

citizens” go into politics to right symbolic wrongs; but the money and

other supports which make them viable as politicians is usually nonsym-

bolic money.

Those who come to the forefront of local government (and those to

whom they are directly responsive), therefore, are not statistically repre-

sentative of the local population as a whole, nor even representative of the

social classes which produce them. The issues they introduce into public

discourse are not representative either. As noted by Edelman, the distribu-

tive issues, the matters which bring people to power, are more or less

deliberately dropped from public discourse (see Schattschneider 1960).

The issues which are allowed to be discussed and the positions which the

politicians take on them derive from the world views of those who come

from certain sectors of the business and professional class and the need

which they have to whip up public sentiment without allowing distributive

issues to become part of public discussion. It follows that any political

change which succeeded in replacing the land business as the key determi-

nant of the local political dynamic would simultaneously weaken the power

of one of the more reactionary political forces in the society, thereby affect-

ing outcomes with respect to those other symbolic issues which manage to

gain so much attention. Thus, should such a change occur, there would

likely be more progressive positions taken on civil liberties, and less

harassment of welfare recipients, social “deviants,” and other defenseless

victims.

LIABILITIES OF THE GROWTH MACHINE

Emerging trends are tending to enervate the locality growth machines.

First is the increasing suspicion that in many areas, at many historical

moments, growth benefits only a small proportion of local residents. Growth

almost always brings with it the obvious problems of increased air and

water pollution, traffic congestion, and overtaxing of natural amenities. These dysfunctions become increasingly important and visible as increased

consumer income fulfills people’s other needs and as the natural cleansing

capacities of the environment are progressively overcome with deleterious

material. While it is by no means certain that growth and increased den-

sity inevitably bring about social pathologies (see Fischer, Baldassare, and Ofshe 1974), growth does make such pathologies more difficult to deal

with. For example, the larger the jurisdiction, the more difficult it becomes

to achieve the goal of school integration without massive busing schemes. As increasing experience with busing makes clear, small towns can more

easily have interracial schools, whether fortuitously through spatial prox- imity or through managed programs.

318

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

In addition, the weight of research evidence is that growth often costs

existing residents more money. Evidently, at various population levels, points of diminishing returns are crossed such that additional increments

lead to net revenue losses. A 1970 study for the city of Palo Alto, Cali-

fornia, indicated that it was substantially cheaper for that city to acquire

at full market value its foothill open space than to allow it to become an

“addition” to the tax base (Livingston and Blayney 1971). A study of

Santa Barbara, California, demonstrated that additional population growth

would require higher property taxes, as well as higher utility costs (Appel-

baum et al. 1974). Similar results on the costs of growth have been ob-

tained in studies of Boulder, Colorado (cited in Finkler 1972), and Ann

Arbor, Michigan (Ann Arbor City Planning Department 1972) .14 Sys-

tematic analyses of government costs as a function of city size and growth

have been carried out under a number of methodologies, but the use of

the units of analysis most appropriate for comparison (urban areas)

yields the finding that the cost is directly related both to size of place

and rate of growth, at least for middle-size cities (see Follett 1976; Appel-

baum 1976). Especially significant are per capita police costs, which

virtually all studies show to be positively related to both city size and rate

of growth (see Appelbaum et al. 1974; Appelbaum 1976).

Although damage to the physical environment and costs of utilities and

governmental services may rise with size of settlement, “optimal” size is

obviously determined by the sorts of values which are to be maximized

(see Duncan 1957). It may indeed be necessary to sacrifice clean air to

accumulate a population base large enough to support a major opera com-

pany. But the essential point remains that growth is certainly less of a

financial advantage to the taxpayer than is conventionally depicted, and

that most people’s values are, according to the survey evidence (Hoch 1972, p. 280; Finkler 1972, pp. 2, 23; Parke and Westoff 1972; Mazie and

Rowlings 1973; Appelbaum et al. 1974, pp. 4.2-4.6) more consistent with

small places than large. Indeed, it is rather clear that some substantial

portion of the migrations to the great metropolitan areas of the last decade

has been more in spite of people’s values than because of them. In the

recent words of Sundquist: “The notion commonly expressed that Ameri-

cans have ‘voted with their feet’ in favor of the great cities is, on the basis

of every available sampling, so much nonsense.. . . What is called ‘freedom

of choice’ is, in sum, freedom of employer choice or, more precisely, free-

dom of choice for that segment of the corporate world that operates mobile

14 A useful bibliography of growth evaluation studies is Agelasto and Perry (undated). A study with findings contrary to those reported here (Gruen and Gruen Associates 1972) limits cost evaluation to only three municipal services and was carried out in a city which had already made major capital expenditures that provided it with huge unused capacities in water, schools, and sewage.

319

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

enterprises. The real question, then, is whether freedom of corporate choice

should be automatically honored by government policy at the expense of

freedom of individual choice where those conflict” (1975, p. 258).

Taking all the evidence together, it is certainly a rather conservative

statement to make that under many circumstances growth is a liability

financially and in quality of life for the majority of local residents. Under

such circumstances, local growth is a transfer of quality of life and wealth

from the local general public to a certain segment of the local elite. To

raise the question of wisdom of growth in regard to any specific locality

is hence potentially to threaten such a wealth transfer and the interests of those who profit by it.

THE PROBLEMS OF JOBS

Perhaps the key ideological prop for the growth machine, especially in

terms of sustaining support from the working-class majority (Levison

1974), is the claim that growth “makes jobs.” This claim is aggressively promulgated by developers, builders, and chambers of commerce; it be- comes a part of the statesman talk of editorialists and political officials. Such people do not speak of growth as useful to profits-rather, they speak of it as necessary for making jobs. But local growth does not, of course,

make jobs: it distributes jobs. The United States will see next year the

construction of a certain number of new factories, office units, and high- ways-regardless of where they are put. Similarly, a given number of auto-

mobiles, missiles, and lampshades will be made, regardless of where they are manufactured. Thus, the number of jobs in this society, whether in

the building trades or any other economic sector, will be determined by rates of investment return, federal decisions affecting the money supply, and other factors having very little to do with local decision making. All

that a locality can do is to attempt to guarantee that a certain proportion of newly created jobs will be in the locality in question. Aggregate empioy- ment is thus unaffected by the outcome of this competition among localities to “make” jobs.

The labor force is essentially a single national pool; workers are mobile and generally capable of taking advantage of employment opportunities emerging at geographically distant points.15 As jobs develop in a fast- growing area, the unemployed will be attracted from other areas in suffi- cient numbers not only to fill those developing vacancies but also to form

15 I am not arguing that the labor force is perfectly mobile, as indeed there is strong evidence that mobility is limited by imperfect information, skill limitations, and cultural and family ties. The argument is rather that the essential mobility of the labor force is sufficiently pronounced to make programs of local job creation largely irrelevant to long-term rates of unemployment.

320

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

a work-force sector that is continuously unemployed. Thus, just as local

growth does not affect aggregate employment, it likely has very little long-

term impact upon the local rate of unemployment. Again, the systematic

evidence fails to show any advantage to growth: there is no tendency for

either larger places or more rapidly growing ones to have lower unemploy-

ment rates than other kinds of urban areas. In fact, the tendency is for

rapid growth to be associated with higher rates of unemployment (for

general documentation, see Follett 1976; Appelbaum 1976; Hadden and

Borgatta 1965, p. 108; Samuelson 1942; Sierra Club of San Diego 1973).16

This pattern of findings is vividly illustrated through inspection of rele-

vant data on the most extreme cases of urban growth: those SMSAs which

experienced the most rapid rates of population increase over the last two

intercensus decades. Tables 1 and 2 show a comparison of population

growth and unemployment rates in the 25 areas which grew fastest during

the 1950-60 and 1960-70 periods. In the case of both decade comparisons,

half of the urban areas had unemployment rates above the national figure

for all SMSAs.

Even the 25 slowest-growing (1960-70) SMSAs failed to experience

particularly high rates of unemployment. Table 3 reveals that although

all were places of net migration loss less than half of the SMSAs of this group had unemployment rates above the national mean at the decade’s

end.

Just as striking is the comparison of growth and unemployment rates

for all SMSAs in California during the 1960-66 period-a time of general

boom in the state. Table 4 reveals that among all California metropolitan

areas there is no significant relationship (r = -17, z – .569) between 1960-66 growth rates and the 1966 unemployment rate. Table 4 is also

instructive (and consistent with other tables) in revealing that while there

is a wide divergence in growth rates across metropolitan areas, there is no

comparable variation in the unemployment rates, all of which cluster

within the relatively narrow range of 4.3%o-6.5%. Consistent with my previous argument, I take this as evidence that the mobility of labor tends

to flatten out cross-SMSA unemployment rates, regardless of widely diverg-

ing rates of locality growth. Taken together, the data indicate that local

population growth is no solution to the problem of local unemployment.

It remains possible that for some reason certain specific rates of growth

may be peculiarly related to lower rates of unemployment and that the

measures used in this and cited studies are insensitive to these patterns.

16 This lack of relationship between local population change and unemployment has led others to conclusions similar to my own: “Economists unanimously have agreed that the only jurisdiction that should be concerned with the effects of its policies on the level of employment is the Federal government. Small jurisdictions do not have the power to effect significant changes in the level of unemployment” (Levy and Arnold 1972, p. 95).

321

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

TABLE 1

GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES FOR 25 FASTEST-GROWING SMSAs, 1950-60 (%)

Unemployment Rate,

Metropolitan Area Rate of Growth 1960

1. Ft. Lauderdale-Hollywood, Fla …………. 297.9 4.7 2. Anaheim-Santa Ana-Garden Grove, Calif. .. 225.6 4.6 3. Las Vegas, Nev . …………………….. 163.0 6.7* 4. Midland, Tex . ……………………… 162.6 4.9 5. Orlando, Fla . ………………………. 124.6 5.1 6. San Jose, Calif . …………………….. 121.1 7.0* 7. Odessa, Tex . ……………………….. 116.1 5.6* 8. Phoenix, Ariz . ……………………… 100.0 4.7 9. W. Palm Beach, Fla .98.9 4.8 10. Colorado Springs, Colo .b………………. 92.9 6.1* 11. Miami, Fla . ………………………… 88.9 7.3* 12. Tampa-St. Petersburg, Fla . ……………. 88.8 5.1 13. Tucson, Ariz . ………………………. 88.1 5.9* 14. Albuquerque, N. Mex . ……………….. 80.0 4.5 15. San Bernadino-Riverside-Ontario, Calif. 79.3 6.7* 16. Sacramento, Calif . …………………… 74.0 6.1* 17. Albany, Ga . ……………………….. 73.5 4.4 18. Santa Barbara, Calif . ………………… 72.0 3.6 19. Amarillo, Tex . ……………………… 71.6 3.3 20. Reno, Nev. ………………………… 68.8 6.1* 21. Lawton, Okla. 64.6 5.5* 22. Lake Charles, La .62.3 7.8* 23. El Paso, Tex .61.1 6.4* 24. Pensacola, Fla .54.9 5.3* 25. Lubbock, Tex …………. . . .. 54.7 3.9 Total U.S . .18.5 5.2

SOURCE.-U.S. Bureau of the Census 1962, tables 33, 154. * Unemployment rate above SMSA national mean.

Similarly, growth in certain types of industries may be more likely than

growth in others to stimulate employment without attracting migrants. It may also be possible that certain population groups, by reason of cul-

tural milieu, are less responsive to mobility options than others and thus

provide bases for exceptions to the general argument I am advancing. The

present analysis does not preclude such future findings but does assert, minimally, that the argument that growth makes jobs is contradicted by

the weight of evidence that is available.17 I conclude that for the average worker in a fast-growing region job

security has much the same status as for a worker in a slower-growing

region: there is a surplus of workers over jobs, generating continuous

17It is also true that this evidence is based on federal data, accumulated through the work of socially and geographically disparate persons who had purposes at hand different from mine. This important reservation can only be dealt with by noting that the findings were consistent with the author’s theoretical expectations, rather than antecedents of them. At a minimum, the results throw the burden of proof on those who would argue the opposite hypothesis.

322

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

TABLE 2

GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES OF THE 25 FASTEST-GROWING SMSAs, 1960-70 (%)

Unemployment Rate, Metropolitan Area Rate of Growth 1970

1. Las Vegas, Nev . ……………………. 115.2 5.2* 2. Anaheim-Santa Ana-Garden Grove, Calif. .. 101.8 5.4* 3. Oxnard-Ventura, Calif . ……………….. 89.0 5.9* 4. Ft. Lauderdale-Hollywood, Fla . ………… 85.7 3.4 5. San Jose, Calif . …………………….. 65.8 5.8* 6. Colorado Springs, Colo .b……………… 64.2 5.5* 7. Santa Barbara, Calif . ………………… 56.4 6.4* 8. W. Palm Beach, Fla . ………………… 52.9 3.0 9. Nashua, N.H . ………………………. 47.8 2.8 10. Huntsville, Ala .46.6 4.4 11. Columbia, Mo .45.8 2.4 12. Phoenix, Ariz .45.8 3.9 13. Danbury, Conn .44.3 4.2 14. Fayetteville, Ark .42.9 5.2* 15. Reno, Nev .42.9 6.2* 16. San Bernadino-Riverside-Ontario, Calif . 41.2 5.9* 17. Houston, Tex .40.0 3.0 18. Austin, Tex .39.3 3.1 19. Dallas, Tex .39.0 3.0 20. Santa Rosa, Calif .39.0 7.3* 21. Tallahassee, Fla. 38.8 3.0 22. Washington, D.C . 37.8 2.7 23. Atlanta, Ga. 36.7 3.0 24. Ann Arbor, Mich .35.8 5.0* 25. Miami, Fla .35.6 3.7 Total U.S . …………………………….. 16.6 4.3

SOURCE.-U.S. Bureau of the Census 1972, table 3, SMSAs. * Unemployment rate above the SMSA national mean.

anxiety over unemployment18 and the effective depressant on wages which any lumpenproletariat of unemployed and marginally employed tends to exact (see, e.g., Bonacich 1975). Indigenous workers likely receive little benefit from the growth machine in terms of jobs; their “native” status gives them little edge over the “foreign” migrants seeking the additional jobs which may develop. Instead, they are interchangeable parts of the labor pool, and the degree of their job insecurity is expressed in the local unemployment rate, just as is the case for the nonnative worker. Ironically, it is probably this very anxiety which often leads workers, or at least their union spokespeople, to support enthusiastically employers’ preferred poli- cies of growth. It is the case that an actual decline in local job opportuni- ties, or economic growth not in proportion to natural increase, might induce the hardship of migration. But this price is not the same as, and is less severe than, the price of simple unemployment. It could also rather

18 For an insightful treatment of joblessness with respect to the majority of the American work force, see Levison (1974).

323

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

TABLE 3

GROWTH, UNEMPLOYMENT, AND NET MIGRATION RATES FOR THE 25 SLOWEST-GROWING SMSAs, 1960-70

(%)

Rate of Net Unemployment, SMSA Growth Migration 1970

1. Abilene, Tex. ………….. ………….. -5.3 -19.7 3.6 2. Altoona, Pa. …………… ………….. -1.4 – 6.6 3.5 3. Amarillo, Tex. ………… …………… -3.4 -19.5 3.4 4. Brownsville-Harlingen-San Benito, Tex. -7.1 -32.1 6.6* 5. Charleston, W. Va ……………………. -9.3 -19.0 4.1 6. Duluth-Superior, Minn.-Wis . ………….. -4.1 -10.9 7.3* 7. Gadsden, Ala. …………. …………… -2.9 -12.4 7.3* 8. Huntington-Ashland, W. Va.-Ky.-Ohio ….. -0.4 – 9.7 5.1* 9. Jersey City, N.J. ……….. ………….. -0.5 – 7.5 4.7* 10. Johnstown, Pa . …………………….. -6.4 -11.8 4.9* 11. McAllen-Pharr-Edinburgh, Tex . ………… -0.3 -25.4 5.9* 12. Midland, Tex ………… 3.4 -19.1 3.5 13. Montgomery, Ala . …………………… 0.9 -11.1 3.8 14. Odessa, Tex . ……………………….. 0.9 -16.7 4.3 15. Pittsburgh, Pa . …………………….. -0.2 – 7.0 4.3 16. Pueblo, Colo. ………….. ………….. -0.4 -12.3 5.9* 17. St. Joseph, Mo . …………………….. -4.0 – 9.2 3.9 18. Savannah, Ga . ……………………… -0.3 -13.3 4.3 19. Scranton, Pa . ………………………. -0.2 – 1.8 5.2* 20. Sioux City, Iowa ………. …………… -3.2 -13.5 4.4* 21. Steubenville-Weirton, Ohio-W. Va. …….. -1.3 – 8.9 3.7 22. Utica-Rome, MY. ………………….. -1.7 -11.2 5.7* 23. Wheeling, W. Va.-Ohio ……………….. -4.0 – 8.3 4.2 24. Wichita Falls, Tex ……………………. -2.6 -15.1 4.0 25. Wilkes-Barre-Hazleton, Pa. …… ……… -1.3 – 3.5 4.0 Total US. …………..S………………… 16.6 … 4.3

SOURCE.-U.S. Bureau of the Census 1972, table 3, SMSAs. * Unemployment rate above SMSA national mean.

easily be compensated through a relocation subsidy for mobile workers, as is now commonly provided for high-salaried executives by private corpora- tions and in a limited way generally by the federal tax deduction for job- related moving expenses.

Workers’ anxiety and its ideological consequences emerge from the larger fact that the United States is a society of constant substantial job- lessness, with unemployment rates conservatively estimated by the Depart- ment of Commerce at 4%-8%o of that portion of the work force defined as ordinarily active. There is thus a game of musical chairs being played at all times, with workers circulating around the country, hoping to land in an empty chair at the moment the music stops. Increasing the stock of jobs in any one place neither causes the music to stop more frequently nor increases the number of chairs relative to the number of players. The only way effectively to ameliorate this circumstance is to create a full-employ- ment economy, a comprehensive system of drastically increased unemploy- ment insurance, or some other device which breaks the connection between

324

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

TABLE 4

GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES FOR ALL CALIFORNIA SMSAs, 1960-66 (%)

Rate of Average

Growth, Annual Unemployment SMSA 1960-66 Change Rate, 1966

Anaheim-Santa Ana-Garden Grove …….. 65.0 8.3 4.3 Bakersfield .11.1 1.7 5.2 Fresno .12.3 1.9 6.5 Los Angeles-Long Beach .11.9 1.9 4.5 Modesto ………….. ……………… … Oxnard-Ventura .68.8 8.7 6.0 Sacramento .20.0 3.0 5.2 Salinas-Monterey .15.9 2.4 6.1 San Bernadino-Riverside. 27.9 4.0 6.2

San Diego .14.0 2.1 5.1 San Francisco-Oakland .11.1 1.7 4.4 San Jose .44.8 6.1 4.8 Santa Barbara .48.7 6.6 4.5 Santa Rosa …………. ……………. . … … Stockton .12.5 1.9 6.3

Vallejo-Napa .20.6 3.0 4.4 California mean .27.47 3.80 5.25

SOURCES.-For average annual change and rate of growth, U.S. Bureau of the Census 1969, table 2; for unemployment rate, 1966, State of California 1970, table C-10.

a person’s having a livelihood and the remote decisions of corporate execu-

tives. Without such a development, the fear of unemployment acts to make

workers politically passive (if not downright supportive) with respect to

land-use policies, taxation programs, and antipollution nonenforcement

schemes which, in effect, represent income transfers from the general pub- lic to various sectors of the elite (see Whitt 1975). Thus, for many reasons,

workers and their leaders should organize their political might more con-

sistently not as part of the growth coalitions of the localities in which they

are situated, but rather as part of national movements which aim to pro-

vide full employment, income security, and programs for taxation, land

use, and the environment which benefit the vast majority of the population.

They tend not to be doing this at present.

THE PROBLEM OF NATURAL INCREASE

Localities grow in population not simply as a function of migration but also

because of the fecundity of the existing population. Some means are obvi-

ously needed to provide jobs and housing to accommodate such growth-

either in the immediate area or at some distant location. There are ways

of handling this without compounding the environmental and budgetary

problems of existing settlements. First, there are some localities which are,

by many criteria, not overpopulated. Their atmospheres are clean, water

325

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

supplies plentiful, and traffic congestion nonexistent. In fact, in certain

places increased increments of population may spread the costs of existing

road and sewer systems over a larger number of citizens or bring an in-

crease in quality of public education by making rudimentary specialization

possible. In the state of California, for example, the great bulk of the

population lives on a narrow coastal belt in the southern two-thirds of the

state. Thus the northern third of the state consists of a large unpopulated

region rich in natural resources, including electric power and potable water.

The option chosen in California, as evidenced by the state aqueduct, was

to move the water from the uncrowded north to the dense, semiarid south,

thus lowering the environmental qualities of both regions, and at a sub-

stantial long-term cost to the public budget. The opposite course of action

was clearly an option.

The point is that there are relatively underpopulated areas in this coun-

try which do not have “natural” problems of inaccessibility, ugliness, or

lack of population-support resources. Indeed, the nation’s most severely

depopulated areas, the towns of Appalachia, are in locales of sufficient re-

sources and are widely regarded as aesthetically appealing; population out-

migration likely decreased the aesthetic resources of both the migrants to

and residents of Chicago and Detroit, while resulting in the desertion of a

housing stock and utility infrastructure designed to serve a larger popula-

tion. Following from my more general perspective, I see lack of population

in a given area as resulting from the political economic decisions made to

populate other areas instead. If the process were rendered more rational,

the same investments in roads, airports, defense plants, etc., could be made

to effect a very different land-use outcome. Indeed, utilization of such

deliberate planning strategies is the practice in some other societies and

shows some evidence of success (see Sundquist 1975); perhaps it could be made to work in the United States as well.

As a long-term problem, natural increase may well be phased out. Ameri-

can birth rates have been steadily decreasing for the last several years, and we are on the verge of a rate providing for zero population growth. If a

stable population actually is achieved, a continuation of the present inter-

local competitive system will result in the proliferation of ghost towns and

unused capital stocks as the price paid for the growth of the successful

competing units. This will be an even more clearly preposterous situation than the current one, which is given to produce ghost towns only on occa- sion.

THE EMERGING COUNTERCOALITION

Although growth has been the dominant ideology in most localities in the United States, there has always been a subversive thread of resistance.

326

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

Treated as romantic, or as somehow irrational (see White and White 1962), this minority long was ignored, even in the face of accumulating journalis-

tic portrayals of the evils of bigness. But certainly it was an easy observa-

tion to make that increased size was related to high levels of pollution,

traffic congestion, and other disadvantages. Similarly, it was easy enough

to observe that tax rates in large places were not generally less than those

in small places; although it received little attention, evidence that per

capita government costs rise with population size was provided a genera-

tion ago (see Hawley 1951). But few took note, though the very rich,

somehow sensing these facts to be the case, managed to reserve for them-

selves small, exclusive meccas of low density by tightly imposing popula-

tion ceilings (e.g., Beverly Hills, Sands Point, West Palm Beach, Lake

Forest).

In recent years, however, the base of the antigrowth movement has be-

come much broader and in some localities has reached sufficient strength

to achieve at least toeholds of political power. The most prominent cases

seem to be certain university cities (Palo Alto, Santa Barbara, Boulder,

Ann Arbor), all of which have sponsored impact studies documenting the

costs of additional growth. Other localities which have imposed growth

controls tend also to be places of high amenity value (e.g., Ramapo, N.Y.;

Petaluma, Calif.; Boca Raton, Fla.). The antigrowth sentiment has become

an important part of the politics of a few large cities (e.g., San Diego) and

has been the basis of important political careers at the state level (includ-

ing the governorship) in Oregon, Colorado, and Vermont. Given the objec-

tive importance of the issue and the evidence on the general costs of growth,

there is nothing to prevent antigrowth coalitions from similarly gaining

power elsewhere including those areas of the country which are generally

considered to possess lower levels of amenity. Nor is there any reason,

based on the facts of the matter, for these coalitions not to further broaden

their base to include the great majority of the working class in the localities

in which they appear.

But, like all political movements which attempt to rely upon volunteer

labor to supplant political powers institutionalized through a system of

vested economic interest, antigrowth movements are probably more likely

to succeed in those places where volunteer reform movements have a real-

istic constituency-a leisured and sophisticated middle class with a tradi-

tion of broad-based activism, free from an entrenched machine. At least,

this appears to be an accurate profile of those places in which the anti-

growth coalitions have already matured.

Systematic studies of the social make up of the antigrowth activists are

only now in progress (e.g., Fitts 1976), but it seems that the emerging

countercoalition is rooted in the recent environmental movements and re-

lies on a mixture of young activists (some are veterans of the peace and

327

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

civil rights movements), middle-class professionals, and workers, all of

whom see their own tax rates as well as life-styles in conflict with growth.

Important in leadership roles are government employees and those who

work for organizations not dependent on local expansion for profit, either

directly or indirectly. In the Santa Barbara antigrowth movements, for

example, much support is provided by professionals from research and

electronics firms, as well as branch managers of small “high-technology”

corporations. Cosmopolitan in outlook and pecuniary interest, they use

the local community only as a setting for life and work, rather than as an

exploitable resource. Related to this constituency are certain very wealthy

people (particularly those whose wealth derives from the exploitation of

nonlocal environments) who continue a tradition (with some modifications)

of aristocratic conservation.’9

Should it occur, the changes which the death of the growth machine

will bring seem clear enough with respect to land-use policy. Local gov-

ernments will establish holding capacities for their regions and then legis-

late, directly or indirectly, to limit population to those levels. The direction

of any future development will tend to be planned to minimize negative

environmental impacts. The so-called natural process (see Burgess 1925; Hoyt 1939) of land development which has given American cities their present shape will end as the political and economic foundations of such

processes are undermined. Perhaps most important, industrial and business

land users and their representatives will lose, at least to some extent, the

effectiveness of their threat to locate elsewhere should public policies en-

danger the profitability they desire. As the growth machine is destroyed in many places, increasingly it will be the business interests who will be

forced to make do with local policies, rather than the local populations having to bow to business wishes. New options for taxation, creative land- use programs, and new forms of urban services may thus emerge as city government comes to resemble an agency which asks what it can do for its people rather than what it can do to attract more people. More specif- ically, a given industrial project will perhaps be evaluated in terms of its

social utility-the usefulness of the product manufactured-either to the locality or to the society at large. Production, merely for the sake of

local expansion, will be less likely to occur. Hence, there will be some pressure to increase the use value of the country’s production apparatus

and for external costs of production to be borne internally.

19 Descriptions of the social makeup of American environmentalists (who coincide as a group only roughly with the no-growth activists) and of their increasing militancy

are contained in Nash (1967), Bartell (1974), Dunlap and Gale (1972), Faich and Gale (1971). For a journalistic survey of no-growth activities, see Robert Cahn, “Mr. Developer, Someone Is Watching You” (Christian Science Monitor [May 21, 1973], p. 9). A more comprehensive description is contained in Reilly (1973).

328

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

When growth ceases to be an issue, some of the investments made in

the political system to influence and enhance growth will no longer make

sense, thus changing the basis upon which people get involved in govern-

ment. We can expect that the local business elites-led by land developers

and other growth-coalition forces-will tend to withdraw from local pol-

itics. This vacuum may then be filled by a more representative and,

likely, less reactionary activist constituency. It is noteworthy that where

antigrowth forces have established beachheads of power, their programs

and policies have tended to be more progressive than their predecessors’-

on all issues, not just on growth. In Colorado, for example, the environ-

mentalist who led the successful fight against the Winter Olympics also

successfully sponsored abortion reform and other important progressive

causes. The environmentally based Santa Barbara “Citizens Coalition”

(with city government majority control) represents a fusion of the city’s

traditional left and counterculture with other environmental activists. The

result of the no-growth influence in localities may thus be a tendency for

an increasing progressiveness in local politics. To whatever degree local

politics is the bedrock upon which the national political structure rests

(and there is much debate here), there may follow reforms at the national level as well. Perhaps it will then become possible to utilize national insti-

tutions to effect other policies which both solidify the death of the growth

machine at the local level and create national priorities consistent with

the new opportunities for urban civic life. These are speculations based

upon the questionable thesis that a reform-oriented, issue-based citizens’

politics can be sustained over a long period. The historical record is not

consistent with this thesis; it is only emerging political trends in the

most affected localities and the general irrationality of the present urban

system that suggest the alternative possibility is an authentic future.

REFERENCES

Adrian, Charles R., and 0. P. Williams. 1963. Four Cities: A Study in Comparative Policy Making. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

Agelasto, Michael A., II, and Patricia R. Perry. Undated. “The No Growth Contro- versy.” Exchange Bibliography no. 519. Mimeographed. Box 229, Monticello, Ill.: Council of Planning Libraries.

Agger, Robert, Daniel Goldrich, and Bert E. Swanson. 1964. The Rulers and the Ruled: Political Power and Impotence in American Communities. New York: Wiley.

Alonso, William. 1964. “Location Theory.” Pp. 79-81 in Regional Development and Planning, edited by John Friedman and William Alonso. Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press.

Ann Arbor City Planning Department. 1972. The Ann Arbor Growth Study. Ann Arbor, Mich.: City Planning Department.

Appelbaum, Richard. 1976. “City Size and Urban Life: A Preliminary Inquiry into Some Consequences of Growth in American Cities.” Urban Affairs Quarterly.

Appelbaum, Richard, Jennifer Bigelow, Henry Kramer, Harvey Molotch, and Paul Relis. 1974. Santa Barbara: The Impacts of Growth: A Report of the Santa

329

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

Barbara Planning Task Force to the City of Santa Barbara. Santa Barbara, Calif.: Office of the City Clerk. Forthcoming in abridged form as The Effects of Urban Growth: A Population Impact Analysis: New York: Praeger.

Banfield, Edward. 1961. Political Influence. New York: Macmillan. Bartell, Ted. 1974. “Compositional Change and Attitude Change among Sierra Club

Members.” Mimeographed. Los Angeles: UCLA Survey Research Center. Bonacich, Edna. 1975. “Advanced Capitalism and Black/White Race Relations in the

U.S.” Mimeographed. Riverside: Department of Sociology, University of California. Bouma, Donald. 1962. “Analysis of the Social Power Position of a Real Estate Board.”

Social Problems 10 (Fall): 121-32. Brown, Douglas. 1974. Introduction to Urban Economics. New York: Academic Press.

Burgess, Ernest W. 1925. The Growth of the City: An Introduction to a Research Project. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Davis, Kingsley. 1965. “The Urbanization of the Human Population.” Scientific Amer- ican 212 (September): 41-53.

Duncan, Otis Dudley. 1957. “Optimum Size of Cities.” Pp. 759-72 in Cities and Soci- eties, edited by Paul Hatt and Albert Reiss, Jr. New York: Free Press.

Dunlap, Riley E., and Richard P. Gale. 1972. “Politics and Ecology: A Political Pro- file of Student Eco-Activists.” Youth and Society 3 (June): 379-97.

Durr, Fred. 1971. The Urban Economy. Scranton, Pa.: Intext.

Edelman, Murray. 1964. The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.

Fagen, Richard R., and William S. Tuohy. 1972. Politics and Privilege in a Mexican City. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Faich, Ronald G., and Richard Gale. 1971. “Environmental Movement: From Recre- ation to Politics.” Pacific Sociological Review 14 (July): 270-87.

Finkler, Earl. 1972. “No-Growth as a Planning Alternative.” Planning Advisory Re- port No. 283. Chicago: American Society of Planning Officials.

Fischer, Claud, Mark Baldassare, and Richard J. Ofshe. 1974. “Crowding Studies and Urban Life: A Critical Review.” Working Paper no. 242, Institute of Urban and Regional Development, University of California, Berkeley.

Fitts, Amelia. 1976. “No-Growth as a Political Issue.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Los Angeles.

Follett, Ross. 1976. “Social Consequences of Urban Size and Growth: An Analysis of Middle-Size U.S. Urban Areas.” Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, Uni- versity of California, Santa Barbara.

Gruen and Gruen Associates. 1972. Impacts of Growth: An Analytical Framework and Fiscal Examples. Berkeley: California Better Housing Foundation.

Hadden, Jeffrey K., and Edgar F. Borgatta. 1965. American Cities: Their Social Char- acteristics. Chicago: Rand-McNally.

Harris, Carl V. 1976. Political Power in Birmingham, 1871-1921. Memphis: University of Tennessee Press.

Hawley, Amos. 1951. “Metropolitan Population and Municipal Government Expendi- tures in Central Cities.” Journal of Social Issues 7 (January): 100-108.

Hoch, Irving. 1972. “Urban Scale and Environmental Quality.” Pp. 231-84 in Pop- ulation, Resources and the Environment. U.S. Commission on Population Growth and the American Future Research Reports, edited by Ronald Ridker, vol. 3. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.

Hoyt, Homer. 1939. The Structure and Growth of Residential Neighborhoods in American Cities. Washington, D.C.: Federal Housing Administration.

Lasswell, Harold. 1936. Politics: Who Gets What, When, How. New York: McGraw- Hill.

Leven, Charles. 1964. “Regional and Interregional Accounts in Perspective.” Papers, Regional Science Association 13: 140-44.

Levison, Andrew. 1974. The Working Class Majority. New York: Coward, McCann & Geoghgan.

Levy, Steven, and Robert K. Arnold. 1972. “An Evaluation of Four Growth Alter-

330

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

The City as a Growth Machine

natives in the City of Milpitas, 1972-1977.” Technical Memorandum Report. Palo Alto, Calif.: Institute of Regional and Urban Studies.

Livingston, Laurence, and John A. Blayney. 1971. “Foothill Environmental Design Study: Open Space vs. Development.” Final Report to the City of Palo Alto. San Francisco: Livingston & Blayney.

McConnell, Grant. 1966. Private Power and American Democracy. New York: Knopf. McKenzie, R. D. 1922. “The Neighborhood: A Study of Local Life in the City of

Columbus, Ohio-Conclusion.” American Journal of Sociology 27 (May): 780-99. Makielski, S. J., Jr. 1966. The Politics of Zoning: The New York Experience. New

York: Columbia University Press. Mazie, Sara Mills, and Steve Rowlings. 1973. “Public Attitude toward Population

Distribution Issues.” Pp. 603-15 in Population Distribution and Policy, edited by Sara Mazie. Washington, D.C.: Commission on Population Growth and the Amer- ican Future.

Molotch, Harvey L. 1967. “Toward a More Human Ecology.” Land Economics 43 (August): 336-41.

. 1973. Managed Integration: Dilemmas of Doing Good in the City. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Mumford, Lewis. 1961. The City in History. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Nash, Roderick. 1967. Wilderness and the American Mind. New Haven, Conn.: Yale

University Press.

Parke, Robert, Jr., and Charles Westoff, eds. 1972. “Aspects of Population Growth Policy.” Report of the U.S. Commission on Population Growth and the American Future. Vol. 6. Washington, D.C.: Commission on Population Growth and the American Future.

Piven, Francis Fox, and Richard Cloward. 1972. Regulating the Poor. New York: Random House.

Reilly, William K., ed. 1973. The Use of Land: A Citizens’ Policy Guide to Urban Growth. New York: Crowell.

Rubin, Lillian. 1972. Busing and Backlash. Berkeley: University of California Press. Samuelson, Paul. 1942. “The Business Cycle and Urban Development.” Pp. 6-17 in

The Problem of the Cities and Towns, edited by Guy Greer. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Schattschneider, E. E. 1960. The Semisovereign People. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

Schulze, Robert 0. 1961. “The Bifurcation of Power in a Satellite City.” Pp. 19-80 in Community Political Systems, edited by Morris Janowitz. New York: Macmillan.

Sierra Club of San Diego. 1973. “Economy, Ecology, and Rapid Population Growth.” Mimeographed. San Diego: Sierra Club.

Spaulding, Charles. 1951. “Occupational Affiliations of Councilmen in Small Cities.” Sociology and Social Research 35 (3): 194-200.

State of California. 1970. California Statistical Abstract, 1970. Sacramento: State of California.

Sundquist, James. 1975. Dispersing Population: What America Can Learn from Europe. Washington, D.C.: Brookings.

Suttles, Gerald. 1972. The Social Construction of Communities. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Tolchin, Martin, and Susan Tolchin. 1971. To the Victor. New York: Random House. U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1962. Census of Population. Vol. 1, pt. 1. Washington,

D.C.: Government Printing Office. . 1969. Current Population Reports, Population Estimates and Projections.

Series P-25, no. 427 (July 31). Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office. . 1972. County and City Data Book. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing

Office.

Wade, Richard. 1969. The Urban Frontier: The Rise of Western Cities. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Walton, John. 1970. “A Systematic Survey of Community Power Research.” Pp. 443-

331

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

 

American Journal of Sociology

64 in The Structure of Community Power, edited by Michael Aiken and Paul Mott. New York: Random House.

White, Morton, and Lucie White. 1962. The Intellectual versus the City. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard and M.I.T. Press.

Whitt, J. Allen. 1975. “Means of Movement: The Politics of Modern Transportation Systems.” Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Sociology, University of California, Santa Barbara.

Wirth, Louis. 1938. “Urbanism as a Way of Life.” American Journal of Sociology 44 (July): 1-14.

Wyner, Allen. 1967. “Governor-Salesman.” National Civic Review 61 (February): 81-86.

332

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Mon, 05 Feb 2018 22:20:06 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

 

  • Contents
    • p. 309
    • p. 310
    • p. 311
    • p. 312
    • p. 313
    • p. 314
    • p. 315
    • p. 316
    • p. 317
    • p. 318
    • p. 319
    • p. 320
    • p. 321
    • p. 322
    • p. 323
    • p. 324
    • p. 325
    • p. 326
    • p. 327
    • p. 328
    • p. 329
    • p. 330
    • p. 331
    • p. 332
  • Issue Table of Contents
    • American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 82, No. 2 (Sep., 1976) pp. 291-511
      • Front Matter [pp. ]
      • Communities, Associations, and the Supply of Collective Goods [pp. 291-308]
      • The City as a Growth Machine: Toward a Political Economy of Place [pp. 309-332]
      • Industrialization and the Stratification of Cities in Suburban Regions [pp. 333-348]
      • Logan on Molotch and Molotch on Logan: Notes on the Growth Machine-Toward a Comparative Political Economy of Place [pp. 349-352]
      • Varieties of Growth Strategy: Some Comments on Logan [pp. 352-355]
      • The Anomie of Affluence: A Post-Mertonian Conception [pp. 356-378]
      • Research Note
        • Race, Achievement, and Delinquency: A Further Look at Delinquency in a Birth Cohort [pp. 379-387]
      • Commentary and Debate
        • An Assessment of Garnier and Hazelrigg’s Paper on Intergenerational Mobility in France [pp. 388-398]
        • Reply to Daniel Bertaux’s Assessment [pp. 398-411]
        • Some Comments on Ritter and Hargens’s “Test of the Asymmetry Hypothesis” [pp. 411-415]
        • Reply to Schneider [pp. 415-417]
        • Economy, Polity, and Monotheism: Reply to Swanson [pp. 418-421]
        • Comment on Underhill’s Reply [pp. 421-423]
        • Ethnicity and Participation: A Commentary [pp. 423-427]
      • Review Essay
        • Individual Rights and the State [pp. 428-442]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 443-448]
      • Book Reviews
        • Review: untitled [pp. 449-451]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 452-458]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 458-460]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 460-462]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 462-465]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 465-467]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 467-469]
        • Review: untitled [pp. 469-472]

Get Professional Assignment Help Cheaply

Buy Custom Essay

Are you busy and do not have time to handle your assignment? Are you scared that your paper will not make the grade? Do you have responsibilities that may hinder you from turning in your assignment on time? Are you tired and can barely handle your assignment? Are your grades inconsistent?

Whichever your reason is, it is valid! You can get professional academic help from our service at affordable rates. We have a team of professional academic writers who can handle all your assignments.

Why Choose Our Academic Writing Service?

  • Plagiarism free papers
  • Timely delivery
  • Any deadline
  • Skilled, Experienced Native English Writers
  • Subject-relevant academic writer
  • Adherence to paper instructions
  • Ability to tackle bulk assignments
  • Reasonable prices
  • 24/7 Customer Support
  • Get superb grades consistently

Online Academic Help With Different Subjects

Literature

Students barely have time to read. We got you! Have your literature essay or book review written without having the hassle of reading the book. You can get your literature paper custom-written for you by our literature specialists.

Finance

Do you struggle with finance? No need to torture yourself if finance is not your cup of tea. You can order your finance paper from our academic writing service and get 100% original work from competent finance experts.

Computer science

Computer science is a tough subject. Fortunately, our computer science experts are up to the match. No need to stress and have sleepless nights. Our academic writers will tackle all your computer science assignments and deliver them on time. Let us handle all your python, java, ruby, JavaScript, php , C+ assignments!

Psychology

While psychology may be an interesting subject, you may lack sufficient time to handle your assignments. Don’t despair; by using our academic writing service, you can be assured of perfect grades. Moreover, your grades will be consistent.

Engineering

Engineering is quite a demanding subject. Students face a lot of pressure and barely have enough time to do what they love to do. Our academic writing service got you covered! Our engineering specialists follow the paper instructions and ensure timely delivery of the paper.

Nursing

In the nursing course, you may have difficulties with literature reviews, annotated bibliographies, critical essays, and other assignments. Our nursing assignment writers will offer you professional nursing paper help at low prices.

Sociology

Truth be told, sociology papers can be quite exhausting. Our academic writing service relieves you of fatigue, pressure, and stress. You can relax and have peace of mind as our academic writers handle your sociology assignment.

Business

We take pride in having some of the best business writers in the industry. Our business writers have a lot of experience in the field. They are reliable, and you can be assured of a high-grade paper. They are able to handle business papers of any subject, length, deadline, and difficulty!

Statistics

We boast of having some of the most experienced statistics experts in the industry. Our statistics experts have diverse skills, expertise, and knowledge to handle any kind of assignment. They have access to all kinds of software to get your assignment done.

Law

Writing a law essay may prove to be an insurmountable obstacle, especially when you need to know the peculiarities of the legislative framework. Take advantage of our top-notch law specialists and get superb grades and 100% satisfaction.

What discipline/subjects do you deal in?

We have highlighted some of the most popular subjects we handle above. Those are just a tip of the iceberg. We deal in all academic disciplines since our writers are as diverse. They have been drawn from across all disciplines, and orders are assigned to those writers believed to be the best in the field. In a nutshell, there is no task we cannot handle; all you need to do is place your order with us. As long as your instructions are clear, just trust we shall deliver irrespective of the discipline.

Are your writers competent enough to handle my paper?

Our essay writers are graduates with bachelor's, masters, Ph.D., and doctorate degrees in various subjects. The minimum requirement to be an essay writer with our essay writing service is to have a college degree. All our academic writers have a minimum of two years of academic writing. We have a stringent recruitment process to ensure that we get only the most competent essay writers in the industry. We also ensure that the writers are handsomely compensated for their value. The majority of our writers are native English speakers. As such, the fluency of language and grammar is impeccable.

What if I don’t like the paper?

There is a very low likelihood that you won’t like the paper.

Reasons being:

  • When assigning your order, we match the paper’s discipline with the writer’s field/specialization. Since all our writers are graduates, we match the paper’s subject with the field the writer studied. For instance, if it’s a nursing paper, only a nursing graduate and writer will handle it. Furthermore, all our writers have academic writing experience and top-notch research skills.
  • We have a quality assurance that reviews the paper before it gets to you. As such, we ensure that you get a paper that meets the required standard and will most definitely make the grade.

In the event that you don’t like your paper:

  • The writer will revise the paper up to your pleasing. You have unlimited revisions. You simply need to highlight what specifically you don’t like about the paper, and the writer will make the amendments. The paper will be revised until you are satisfied. Revisions are free of charge
  • We will have a different writer write the paper from scratch.
  • Last resort, if the above does not work, we will refund your money.

Will the professor find out I didn’t write the paper myself?

Not at all. All papers are written from scratch. There is no way your tutor or instructor will realize that you did not write the paper yourself. In fact, we recommend using our assignment help services for consistent results.

What if the paper is plagiarized?

We check all papers for plagiarism before we submit them. We use powerful plagiarism checking software such as SafeAssign, LopesWrite, and Turnitin. We also upload the plagiarism report so that you can review it. We understand that plagiarism is academic suicide. We would not take the risk of submitting plagiarized work and jeopardize your academic journey. Furthermore, we do not sell or use prewritten papers, and each paper is written from scratch.

When will I get my paper?

You determine when you get the paper by setting the deadline when placing the order. All papers are delivered within the deadline. We are well aware that we operate in a time-sensitive industry. As such, we have laid out strategies to ensure that the client receives the paper on time and they never miss the deadline. We understand that papers that are submitted late have some points deducted. We do not want you to miss any points due to late submission. We work on beating deadlines by huge margins in order to ensure that you have ample time to review the paper before you submit it.

Will anyone find out that I used your services?

We have a privacy and confidentiality policy that guides our work. We NEVER share any customer information with third parties. Noone will ever know that you used our assignment help services. It’s only between you and us. We are bound by our policies to protect the customer’s identity and information. All your information, such as your names, phone number, email, order information, and so on, are protected. We have robust security systems that ensure that your data is protected. Hacking our systems is close to impossible, and it has never happened.

How our Assignment Help Service Works

1. Place an order

You fill all the paper instructions in the order form. Make sure you include all the helpful materials so that our academic writers can deliver the perfect paper. It will also help to eliminate unnecessary revisions.

2. Pay for the order

Proceed to pay for the paper so that it can be assigned to one of our expert academic writers. The paper subject is matched with the writer’s area of specialization.

3. Track the progress

You communicate with the writer and know about the progress of the paper. The client can ask the writer for drafts of the paper. The client can upload extra material and include additional instructions from the lecturer. Receive a paper.

4. Download the paper

The paper is sent to your email and uploaded to your personal account. You also get a plagiarism report attached to your paper.

smile and order essay GET A PERFECT SCORE!!! smile and order essay Buy Custom Essay


Place your order
(550 words)

Approximate price: $22

Calculate the price of your order

550 words
We'll send you the first draft for approval by September 11, 2018 at 10:52 AM
Total price:
$26
The price is based on these factors:
Academic level
Number of pages
Urgency
Basic features
  • Free title page and bibliography
  • Unlimited revisions
  • Plagiarism-free guarantee
  • Money-back guarantee
  • 24/7 support
On-demand options
  • Writer’s samples
  • Part-by-part delivery
  • Overnight delivery
  • Copies of used sources
  • Expert Proofreading
Paper format
  • 275 words per page
  • 12 pt Arial/Times New Roman
  • Double line spacing
  • Any citation style (APA, MLA, Chicago/Turabian, Harvard)

Our guarantees

Delivering a high-quality product at a reasonable price is not enough anymore.
That’s why we have developed 5 beneficial guarantees that will make your experience with our service enjoyable, easy, and safe.

Money-back guarantee

You have to be 100% sure of the quality of your product to give a money-back guarantee. This describes us perfectly. Make sure that this guarantee is totally transparent.

Read more

Zero-plagiarism guarantee

Each paper is composed from scratch, according to your instructions. It is then checked by our plagiarism-detection software. There is no gap where plagiarism could squeeze in.

Read more

Free-revision policy

Thanks to our free revisions, there is no way for you to be unsatisfied. We will work on your paper until you are completely happy with the result.

Read more

Privacy policy

Your email is safe, as we store it according to international data protection rules. Your bank details are secure, as we use only reliable payment systems.

Read more

Fair-cooperation guarantee

By sending us your money, you buy the service we provide. Check out our terms and conditions if you prefer business talks to be laid out in official language.

Read more
error: Content is protected !!
Open chat
1
Need assignment help? You can contact our live agent via WhatsApp using +1 718 717 2861

Feel free to ask questions, clarifications, or discounts available when placing an order.
  +1 718 717 2861           + 44 161 818 7126           [email protected]
  +1 718 717 2861         [email protected]